Must It Keep Getting Worse? by
ANDREW LEVINE DEC 11, 2013 http://www.counterpunch.org/2013/12/11/must-it-keep-getting-worse/ ANDREW LEVINE is a Senior
Scholar at the Institute for Policy Studies, the author most recently of THE
AMERICAN IDEOLOGY (Routledge) and POLITICAL KEY WORDS (Blackwell) as well as of
many other books and articles in political philosophy. His most recent book is In Bad Faith:
WhatÕs Wrong With the Opium of the People It must be hard for
people who came of age politically during the past thirty-five years to
appreciate how it used to be taken for granted that increasing productivity
would bring increasing wellbeing to the vast majority – higher wages and
salaries, better social insurance programs, better public education, better
pensions, and the like. It was
taken for granted too that national, state and local governments would be run
efficiently on fiscally sound bases – that, when necessary, taxes would
go up as well as down, and that the tax system would be generally progressive. In those days too, the idea that a
major city like Detroit would go bankrupt seemed about as likely as that a
meteor would flatten it.
And no one expected that, in the near future,
the very rich would enrich themselves egregiously, as
they had in earlier eras, while the vast majority would become worse off.
The expectation instead was that economic inequality would continue to
wane.
There were anti-capitalists
in those bygone days, many more than now; but few of them thought that life
under capitalism was becoming harder to bear. Plainly, it was not. Their
idea was that a socialist alternative would be better still – that it
would attend to fundamental human needs without having to rely on wasteful
military spending or irrational consumerism to keep the economy on track.
Under socialism, work could
become more meaningful and other human endeavors more fulfilling and ennobling.
For anti-capitalists in the first three decades of the post-War period, it
wasnÕt so much a matter of escaping from a burning house as moving to a better
neighborhood. However, with the
house not on fire, anti-capitalism never quite gained mass acceptance; most
people were content to stay in the old neighborhood, and either to leave it as
is or to try to make it better. It
was not just that the Soviet model scared people away from more radical
alternatives. It was also that prosperity and good order were generally
on the rise, and there was every reason to think that progress would
continue. Change is risky; why chance it?
On that last point, there was
widespread agreement. It was
assumed, across the political spectrum, that at least some of the most
debilitating kinks and flaws of earlier versions of capitalism could be worked
through; that capitalism with a human face was a live prospect and already, in
many respects, an actual fact. European social democracy led the way.
However it was much the same in all developed capitalist countries, including
the United States.
To be sure, the American case
was unusual in several respects.
During those decades, capitalist countries other than the United States
(and, to a lesser extent, Canada, New Zealand and Australia) were still, for
the most part, ethnically and culturally homogeneous. The idea that oneÕs
fellow citizens were brothers and sisters under the skin therefore came
naturally; the nation was the family writ large. The United States was
too diverse for that; solidarity was always a struggle. Also, with its legacy of slavery and
its on-going continuations, there were severe racial divisions in the United
States that had no real counterparts in other developed countries. To the
extent that, despite everything, the American nation was a family, it was a
dysfunctional one.
Ethnic and cultural diversity
forced American reformers to become coalition builders, mediators of group
interests that did not always coincide; while
institutional racism limited the scope and depth of their projects.
Reformers in more homogeneous societies had smoother going. America was also unusual –
exceptional, according to the literal meaning of the term – for not
having made universal health care a right like, say, public education through
high school. This is why, to this day, the United States (with or without
Obamacare) does not provide free (or nearly free)
health care for all; why it is decades behind other
countries. For that anomaly, the
American Medical Association was, at first, the main culprit. Nowadays,
private insurance companies and other health care profiteers have taken the
lead in keeping progress at bay. They operate with bipartisan support and
with a friend in the White House. Nevertheless, they are not now and
never were the only problem.
Historical circumstances also
played a role. World War II decimated Europe and Japan, at the same time
that it rescued the American economy. Health care provision, like
everything else, was therefore in shambles elsewhere; in the United States, it
was in as good shape as it had ever been. And because there were wage and
price controls imposed during the War years, corporations, competing for
workers, could only offer fringe benefits – like health insurance. Therefore, when the citizens of other
capitalist countries were in desperate need of everything, including access to
health care, many American workers already had health insurance. When
wage controls were lifted, health insurance came to be one of the many benefits
won or enhanced through collective bargaining, and it was also a perk some
unions offered their members directly.
For the most part, the labor
movement in the United States favored universal coverage, nevertheless.
But like DC statehood for the Democratic Party, it was an idle aspiration for
which their leaders hardly lifted a finger. Everywhere else, the issue
was or soon became a prime demand.
Other countries had and continue to have their own peculiarities too,
though the American case is undoubtedly the most extreme. Nevertheless,
the similarities swamp the differences. The New Deal-Great Society
liberal settlement was, for all practical purposes, an American version of what
social democratic and labor parties elsewhere were forging. The emergence of capitalist states that
undertake affirmative social policies – beyond the Ònight watchmanÓ and
defense roles of earlier periods – had been in the works for a long
time. But it was not until the Great Depression of the 1930s, and then
more clearly after the Second World War, that the affirmative state came into
its own.
There were many factors that
made this possible: a sense of shared sacrifice brought on by the War; the
possibilities, especially in war-ravaged countries, inherent in starting over
almost from scratch; the specter of (actually existing) Communism which made
economic elites more willing to make concessions than they would otherwise have
been, and the salutary influence of newly invigorated labor movements. In Europe especially, labor movements
were connected historically, and sometimes politically, to Marxist and other
socialist political traditions; in the United States, post-War McCarthyite politics wiped out all remnants of that.
But a liberal-labor coalition nevertheless became a potent political
force. America in the late forties
and early fifties was an extreme case, but radical anti-capitalist politics
was, in varying degrees, suppressed everywhere. Still, in most countries,
including the United States, intellectual and cultural forces friendly to left
alternatives within capitalism were tolerated and even encouraged.
Progressive thinking was
never quite hegemonic, but it was everywhere a pole of attraction and a force
to be reckoned with. And the ideological vestiges of earlier, less humane
capitalist eras were effectively marginalized. Even in the United States,
if anyone defended the kinds of neoliberal views that have now become
mainstream, it was from far out in right field. This was a matter of plain common sense. Developed
capitalist countries were increasingly prosperous, and nearly everyone
benefited. Austerity was an unpleasant, but increasingly distant
memory.
Equality was on the
rise. What reason could there be
to advocate policies certain to counter these developments; policies calculated
to make the rich richer and to reduce the wellbeing not just of workers but also
of the vast majority of the so-called Òmiddle class?Ó There were, of course, timeworn ideological reasons –
the ones that have lately been revived. But they had been repudiated long
ago, and everyone knew it. They therefore had little appeal outside the
most retrograde circles. Hardly anyone wanted to turn the clock back; why
would they? Then the world
changed. * * *
It started sometime during
the Carter administration in the United States, and more or less
contemporaneously in Great Britain. By the time Margaret Thatcher and
then Ronald Reagan assumed power, the process was well underway. In short order, the rest of the world followed suit. The more progressive they had
been, the lower they fell. The trajectory of the Mitterrand government in
France is an extreme case, but there were others as well. The factors that had made progress
possible didnÕt go away overnight. But they were not decisive; and they
were themselves affected by changing circumstances. Social solidarities frayed for many reasons; including
increasing levels of immigration all over the developed world. Before
long, many formerly homogeneous European countries had become multi-ethnic and
multi-cultural conglomerations. Memories of wartime sacrifices dwindled
as well; and the specter of Communism faded and then altogether
disappeared.
But the main factor is that
capitalism succeeded too well in building up productive capacities.
Capitalist firms must grow to survive; they must therefore invest. But after thirty some years of steady
and significant growth, there was more than enough capacity already in place
– not in the sense that all wants could easily be satisfied, far from it;
but in the sense that, given the over-capacity already there and
under-utilized, the profit to be made by investing in more significantly
declined. Capitalists could have
staved off decline, at least for a while, if they had been able to gain a
larger share of the total social product. But, thanks to all the gains
registered in the preceding period, they were able to squeeze workersÕ wages
only so much. Of course, they
still try, and sometimes partially succeed. The service industry is
particularly vulnerable; unskilled service workers in traditionally low paying
jobs therefore bear the brunt. But
in that sector too, there are limits. And so it is that, even in todayÕs
tight job market, workers in the fast food industry – many of whom risk
deportation under the Obama regime — are fighting back.
But squeezing workers wages
as much as circumstances allow is not nearly enough of a solution to the
problem capitalists face. For that, capitalists must call upon the state for
aid. Thanks to Òfree tradeÓ and
obliging tax policies, states in capitalist societies have made it possible for
the capitalists they serve to export manufacturing jobs abroad — to
places where wages are preposterously low. This is not just an American
phenomenon; it is a defining feature of the neoliberal world order.
That sort of fix would have been impossible in the days when the greatest
diagnosticians of capitalismÕs Òlaws of motion,Ó Marxist and otherwise,
predicted the systemÕs imminent, internally driven, demise. But
with advances in transport and communication, and with the robotization
of production processes (machines making machines), it has become eminently
possible. For decades now, capitalists have been taking full advantage. How ironic that technological advances
that could go far towards eliminating burdensome toil as a fact of the human
condition, and that could make high living standards for all a reality,
instead, under capitalismÕs aegis, have just the opposite effect!
They lead to the elimination
of domestic manufacturing jobs, increasing unemployment and underemployment,
and they cause wage levels to stagnate or decline – not just in what
remains of the manufacturing sector, but across the board. One might think that this situation
would be intolerable to too many people, and would therefore be politically
unfeasible. This is a fair
expectation in the long run. But the ready availability of cheap products
made abroad and government policies that encourage the rise of public and
private debt have combined to postpone the inevitable. The days when a single
wage earner could support a family are gone, but heavily indebted two wage
households can still shop up a storm.
Thus cheap goods and debt
servitude replaced rising wages and cultural uplift; this is the new capitalist
way. It seems to be working too,
at least for a while. Except in rare moments of lucidity, the ninety-nine
percent have been lulled into thinking that nothing is terribly wrong –
that the Walmartization of everything is just fine.
The Occupy movements broke through the miasma briefly. But they are now a
distant memory. Meanwhile low wage schlock emporia, Walmarts
and others, are opening up all the time.
But even with an acquiescent public, capitalismÕs problems have not gone
away. Capitalists still must find ways to expand their holdings. They canÕt invest all the newfound
wealth flowing into their coffers thanks to the low wages they pay overseas
workers because capacity is already over-built – even in the countries to
which they have exported domestic jobs. And they canÕt consume it all
because they are already bursting at the seams. But neither can they stand in place. There is
therefore only one thing for them to do with the money they have: they must
gamble with it – not literally in casinos but in their close cousins, the
financial markets that nowadays rule the world.
To that end, capitalists have
created previously undreamed of financial instruments that, when bought and
sold at market-driven prices, generate wealth in their own right; wealth that bears only the most tenuous of connections to
the real, productive economy.
Finance capitalÕs ascendance is a response to the exigencies of the
capitalist mode of production in its current phase. But capitalists
cannot financialize the economy on their own.
They need the state for that.
In the American case, this
means putting all those political contributions to use – to guarantee
that the state will pursue policies conducive to their interests. This is
essential because it is the state that controls how much money there is and
therefore how money can make money without making goods or supplying services
along the way. The deep causes
underlying the need for the financial sector to develop as it has – and,
more generally, for the neoliberal turn — are economic, of course; but it
was politics that gave those causes their efficacy, and it is politics that
will determine what their future consequences will be. * * *
It was the labor
movement that forced a more human face onto capitalism; but financialization
and globalization are neutering organized labor – by eliminating the best
jobs and forcing down wages on the rest. Capitalism has become less egalitarian and less humane as a
result.
Before this process got
underway, the class struggle was fairly transparent; workers produced wealth,
and their distributive shares were set by struggles with capitalists over the
wage rate. The logic of the underlying system and lived experience
generally coincided. Now financial
markets rule; they determine what the direct producersÕ share will be. Governments,
it seems, have no choice but to accommodate to their demands. In this sense, political power too is
neutered; real power lies elsewhere — in global markets that operate
beyond human control. But this is
an illusion. Because the political order is the condition for the
possibility of neoliberal rule, human beings can break free from it – by
defeating it politically. It is an
old truth that bears restating: what human beings have made, human beings can
undo and transform. But that will require a new politics because the politics
people everywhere nowadays regard as ÒnormalÓ is part of the problem. To think otherwise is to succumb to the
biggest illusion of all.
We, in the United States, get
drawn into normal politics more than citizens of most other countries because
our political culture is centered around primary elections that focus on
personalities and general elections that focus on the small, mainly cultural
differences that distinguish our two highly polarized, semi-established
political parties. This is why, at
best, our elections only ratify changes achieved in counter-systemic popular
struggles waged in other venues, not in electoral campaigns. And even that doesnÕt happen
often. The civil rights legislation of the 1960s is the last clear
example. To make matters worse,
our elections inevitably devolve into contests between a Democrat and a
Republican – each wedded to the existing order.
It neednÕt be that way in
theory, but our duopoly party system has become so thoroughly entrenched that,
in practice, it can hardly be otherwise.
At the national level, some of our politicians are corrupt, some are
only feckless, but all of them are beholden in various ways to nefarious
pressure groups and moneyed interests. In a country that regards campaign
contributions as Constitutionally protected forms of free speech, it could
hardly be otherwise. There are, of
course, members of the political class, even at the national level, who are
thoroughly decent and who undoubtedly mean well; it is better that they hold
office than that the others do. But there is little that even the best of
them can do to keep things from getting worse, much less to make them
better. The way forward is not through them. An Obama who really was what Obama seemed to be to the
liberals and ÒmoderatesÓ he fooled five years ago would have been a major
improvement over the Obama we got. Such an Obama, possessed of the
political capital the real Obama squandered, might have succeeded, for example,
in getting genuine universal health insurance through Congress. He might
have diminished AmericaÕs pernicious ÒexceptionalismÓ
to that extent.
But even the Obama liberals
imagined would only have been able to mitigate some of the worst aspects of the
political economic order that globalization and financialization
have afflicted upon us. To do better than that, what we need is a politics that
leaves contests between Democrats and Republicans to those who cannot or will
not transcend the horizons of the electoral circus; a politics that targets the
conditions that make the neoliberal policies both parties support possible.
Until we make that happen, the Age of Obama will continue to
be the norm, no matter who wins next time. Then, in the future as in the
recent past, things will only get worse.
ANDREW LEVINE is a Senior Scholar at the Institute for Policy
Studies, the author most recently of THE AMERICAN IDEOLOGY (Routledge)
and POLITICAL KEY WORDS (Blackwell)
as well as of many other books and articles in political philosophy. His most
recent book is In Bad Faith: WhatÕs Wrong With
the Opium of the People. He was a Professor (philosophy) at the
University of Wisconsin-Madison and a Research Professor (philosophy) at the
University of Maryland-College Park. He is a contributor to Hopeless: Barack Obama and the Politics of Illusion
(AK Press).